a reporting standard for defined contribution pension plans

Transcript

a reporting standard for defined contribution pension plans
Working Paper 143/14
A REPORTING STANDARD FOR DEFINED CONTRIBUTION
PENSION PLANS
Kees de Vaan
Daniele Fano
Herialt Mens
Giovanna Nicodano
A Reporting Standard for Defined Contribution Pension Plans.*
Kees de Vaan
Syntrus Achmea Vermogensbeheer
Herialt Mens
Aegon Asset Management
Daniele Fano
Tor Vergata University
Giovanna Nicodano
Collegio Carlo Alberto, University of Turin
October 2014
Abstract
We propose a method for projecting pension benefits, deriving from DC pension plans and
other funded products, at retirement. Projections highlight how the current choice of asset
allocation impacts on future potential retirement outcomes. The latter are compared with a
money-back benchmark so as to clarify the trade-off between risk and return. After the initial
projections, the pension plan revises its forecasts of retirement benefits on a yearly basis as a
function of its own realized returns. Previous shorter-term projections are also compared to
shorter-term ex-post performance. This simple method is a step towards an industry-reporting
standard that responds to regulators’ quest for helping investors monitor the risk of their future
pension.
∗
We are grateful for helpful suggestions to Keith Ambachteshheer, Pablo Antolin, David Blake, Marie Briére,
Bas Donkers, Theo Nijman, Ambrogio Rinaldi, Peter van de Ven, Arthur Van Soest and to participants in the
11th Workshop On Pensions, Insurance and Savings at Paris Dauphine, the “Werkgroep Pensioencommunicatie,
onzekerheid, en pensioenkeuze” at Aegon in Den Haag and Achmea in Zeist. We thank the EU MOPACT Grant
n. 320333 and Netspar for funding, the European Financial Analyst Association for encouraging this study and
Pioneer Investments for kindly hosting our meetings in Italy.
1
1. Introduction
Defined contribution pension plans around the world report their performance in nonhomogeneous ways to their members (Antolín and Harrison, 2012). A common feature they share
is a focus on the returns obtained in the recent past. This practice does not necessarily convey
information on longer-term returns, even if pension investment is for the long run. On the one
hand, returns on certain assets may be close to unpredictable, in which case their past returns do
not forecast future ones. On the other hand, projecting future outcomes given past performance is
likely to exceed the household’s ability, even if the pension fund invested in assets with
predictable returns. There are very few instances of pension plans that report expectations of
future returns. However, this does not convey to pension members information on the range of
future pension benefits, and on how possible outcomes depend on alternative asset allocations
and levels of contribution.
This paper proposes a method for projecting pension benefits in future years until retirement
(given some contribution installments). Importantly, projections provide the plan member
information about the trade-off between higher returns and higher risk taking. It then elaborates
on how the pension fund may compare its recent realized performance to its previous short-term
forecasts, and revise its projections of benefits at retirement as a function of its own actual
returns.
Our proposal has three main features:
(a) pension forecasts refer to the retirement horizon of the plan member;
(b) both projections and ex-post realized performance are compared to an easy-to-grasp
benchmark;
(c) yearly realized performance is assessed against the pension fund's previous yearly projections.
The first characteristic, "mark-to-retirement", stands in contrast with commonly used reporting
methods. Drawing investors' attention towards longer-term goals may help improve their ability
to allocate their savings. This longer-horizon perspective may indeed counter the investor’s
tendency to pour money into funds with high past returns at monthly or quarterly frequencies
(Del Guercio and Tkac; 2002, Rakowski and Wang, 2009), and more generally to poorly time the
market, which reduces their average returns (Friesen and Sapp, 2007). Moreover, this approach
makes it possible to assess the consistency of goals with the assumed installment plan.
The second characteristic of our framework is represented by the benchmark against which
pension fund performance is evaluated, i.e. a purchasing power equivalent, real terms moneyback indicator. We depart from currently used benchmarks (Lehmann and Timmermann, 2008),
which juxtapose realized fund returns to those of a portfolio with comparable risk exposure. Our
benchmark is closer to the maturity-matched Inflation Indexed Bonds (IIB), that are almost
riskless securities for a long-term investor with the same investment horizon as the bond maturity
(see Bodie and Treussard, 2007). Projections against a riskless comparable allow plan members
to appreciate the upside potential of risky assets, at the same time making them aware of their
downside risk. Clearly, the benchmark we propose (the CPI) is easier to beat for the pension fund
than a portfolio of inflation-linked bonds that usually provide a real return besides the indexation
to inflation of the principal. Primarily, however, our benchmark is easier to project. Returns on
2
IIBs – which ought to be applied to contributions in order to mark-to-retirement the benchmark
return – require reliable inflation-linked bond performance indices that are not currently available
in each country, while the CPI index is one of the most established statistics.
Our proposal also requires the fund to contrast realized risk-return performance against its own
previous projections. The more optimistic the ex ante projections, the worse the current
performance will appear relative to expected outcomes. This feature disciplines pension fund
managers when making initial projections, as plan members may leave the fund ex post if faced
with blatant inconsistencies. We recommend that such an exercise be performed annually,
although longer-term ex-post performance reports on a five- or ten- year basis would easily fit in
our framework.
A key characteristic of our method is tying past performance and projected performance on a
rolling base. In turn, this is simpler when the focus is on returns and financial wealth rather than
pension income. Such focus is a shortcoming in countries, such as the Netherlands or Italy, where
annuitization at retirement is respectively fully or partially compulsory. Conversion into annuities
adds another relevant risk dimension, relating to the interest rate at retirement. We therefore
illustrate information on this (augmented) risk-return trade-off with reference to prospective
pension annuities, too.
This paper is a starting point towards the design of a reporting standard for pension plans and,
more generally, for long-term financial investment plans. This reporting standard would
complement the existing ones, GIPS, that allow for short-term performance comparisons (see
GIPS, 2006), through its focus on longer-term financial investment assessments. With a similar
angle, a recent paper by the Group of Thirty (2013) states that accounting methods that embed a
short-term horizon are a potential impediment to long-term finance, and suggest a new approach
called target-date accounting.
Viceira (2010) and (Bagliano, Fugazza and Nicodano, 2010) respectively suggest a method to
inform on the trade-off between risk and return at retirement and a benchmark for the
performance evaluation of pension funds. Our proposal departs from them in two main ways.
First, it combines in an integrated framework both periodic performance evaluation and longerterm risk return projections. Secondly, it focuses on a benchmark that is easy to understand for
plan beneficiaries.
Traditional performance evaluation scrutinizes managerial skills such as security selection and
market timing that allow asset managers to systematically earn risk-adjusted returns above the
market returns (Lehmann and Timmerman, 2008). Our example assumes away return
predictability and security selection activities– thereby abstracting from abnormal returns. Here,
performance evaluation investigates whether the strategic asset allocation, together with the
chosen contribution path, allows managers to both return the purchasing power of contributions
and reach a desired range of monthly pension payments.
The Chilean Pension Supervisor experiments, since 2012, with a simulator that provides
stochastic projections of future pension benefits (see Antolin and Fuentes, 2012; and Berstein
et al., 2013). Their focus is on re replacement rates at retirement, rather than on cumulated
wealth as in our main proposal. They carefully model stochastic labour income as a function of
3
personal characteristics. On the contrary, we expand on pension income sensitivity to interest
rate risk when we shift from projected pension assets to projected income. Interestingly, the
Chilean experiment reveals that pension members face difficulties understanding information
related to pension risk - even when provided with simple words. This is why we resort to graphs
that highlight the money-back benchmark, so as to convey the idea of both downside and upside
potential.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 below describes our base proposal for a
reporting framework, in real terms. Section 3 - 4 project a monthly pension equivalent instead
of accumulated capital, which may help plan members to understand the reports better. Section
4 discusses alternative inflation and wage growth scenarios. Section 5 indicates possible
extensions. Appendix A addresses the sensitivity of monthly pension projections to interest rate
volatility. Appendix B explains how to report in current euro.
2. A Mark-to-Retirement Reporting Framework
Our reporting framework is composed of a limited number of figures and tables, along with a
model to produce them.
Figure 1 below shows the type of asset allocation across time underlying the model.
Figure 2 reports the possible values of pension assets at retirement (time T) against an easy-tograsp benchmark, at current purchasing power. This picture is prepared at the time the pension
member joins the fund (time 0), under assumptions concerning the distribution of asset returns as
specified below.
Figure 3 reports the possible values of pension assets and of the benchmark after one year (time
1), highlighting the realized value of pension assets. This picture allows the investor to compare
the realized return against the pension fund's initial projections.
Figure 4 repeats the simulation of the distribution of pension assets at retirement, starting from
their current (time 1) realized value1. Table I gathers all maintained assumptions. Tables II and
III report some summary statistics concerning, respectively, time 0 and time 1 projections. The
Figures 3 and 4, along with the corresponding Tables, will be updated every year. They can be
interpreted as mark-to-market and mark-to-retirement, respectively.
Figure 5 shows wage payments in retirement, and the replacement rates. It represents the
translation of the above mentioned pension assets at retirement in an annuity, conditional on the
level of interest rates and given a set of standard actuarial assumptions.
The model is characterized by the following choices, as summarized in Table 1: the asset menu,
which should coincide with the menu adopted by the pension fund; the return distribution; the
asset allocation; the contribution profile; the benchmark; the treatment of transaction costs; real
wage growth; and a set of parameters.
1
As will become clear later, we are still using time 0 euro.
4
In our example, only “stocks” (high-risk assets) and “ten-years duration bonds” (low-risk assets)
belong to the asset menu. We allow real and bond stock returns to be jointly log-normally
distributed with known mean, variance and correlation, as is customary in the literature on longterm asset allocation. Both stock and bond returns are independently distributed in time.
We assume that the plan member contributes a monthly amount until retirement. Our benchmark
capital is the sum of all contributions, capitalized at the expected inflation rate. In our example
we assume that a 20- years- old worker contributes 100 € each month in the first year. With zero
wage growth, benchmark capital at retirement is equal to 48,000 €.
We acknowledge the existence of both transaction costs of new contributions and a yearly fee
levied on Assets Under Management (AUM). We do not compute them when projecting
benchmark capital: in this respect, our benchmark is equivalent to a money-back equivalent sum
in real terms. This benchmark will be compared with the value of accumulated assets net of costs.
Thus, the pension fund beats the benchmark if its real return exceeds its costs.2 Absent any cost,
the minimum real pension fund return needed to meet the benchmark is equal to 0%. It becomes
0.43% to compensate yearly AUM fees equal to 0.4% (compounded quarterly) and transaction
costs on new money, of 0.05%.3
The yearly mean real return on equities is equal to 5.5% with 18% volatility. It is assumed to be
independently distributed in time. The real interest rate on constant maturity bonds is 2.5% with
volatility 3%. The correlation between risky assets and bond returns is set to 0.1.
In the example shown in the first set of tables and graphs, the chosen asset allocation entails 20%
in bonds and 80% in stocks, with quarterly rebalancing, as portrayed in Figure 1.
2.1 Projecting Future Pension Assets and the Risk-Return Trade- Off
This section addresses more specifically the information about the long-term risk return trade-off
given to a new pension plan member, age 25, with T=40 years to retirement. Figure 2 reports
projected pension assets from age 25 to age 65 over 2,000 possible scenarios that originate from a
random drawing of stock and bond returns from their assumed joint distribution.
Our "money-back" benchmark, gross of fund costs, appears in red. Mean accumulated assets
appear in black. This picture clearly conveys the upside potential of equity investing, together
with its downside risk.
The statistics at the bottom (Table II) provide some quantitative information. The first column
indicates the probability of not reaching the "money-back" benchmark (3.35%) after 40 years.
This is the observed proportion of scenarios that end up with accumulated assets below
benchmark. The maximum shortfall with respect to the benchmark is equal to € -23,299.75, while
2
Pension funds often invest in mutual funds, which charge additional fees, instead of individual securities. These
fees should not affect benchmark capital, either. We overlook transaction costs associated with quarterly
rebalancing. Thus our simulations overstate pension fund return projections. Throughout the analysis, we do not
consider distortions induced by taxation. We discuss other maintained assumptions in Section 4.
3
Those figures complete our example, but a regulator may want to establish a cost benchmark.
5
the average of all scenarios ending below the money-back benchmark is € -6,772.41. The second
column reveals that the average amount of accumulated assets is equal to € 177,597.05, while the
minimum equals € 24,747.04. The last four rows report upper and lower percentile boundary
figures: these provide an idea of the accumulated assets associated with highly probable
outcomes on the upside as well as on the downside. For instance, the last two read like “there is a
15% probability that accumulated assets will end below € 76,519.86; and a 5% probability they
will end below € 53,064.12”.
2.2. Reporting Pension Performance One Year Later
Figure 3 allows the pension or investment plan member to assess the performance of her pension
fund one year later. It highlights, with a blue mark, the actual ex-post accumulated assets against
both the projected ones and the "money-back" benchmark in red. In the example, the gross-offees-and-transaction-costs realized return is equal to -30.4%, leaving her with € 1,000 instead of
€ 1,200. Thus, the blue mark appears below the money-back benchmark. This picture does not
depart from the logic of mark-to-market pension assets; however, it allows the plan participant to
acknowledge that the (negative) performance result was among the ones considered possible exante.
In other words, a plan member should understand that there might be large transitory deviations
from the benchmark even in the case of a DC-plan that exactly matches an inflation-indexed
benchmark. The plan will eventually deliver the expected return over the entire period because it
is matched. The next section describes mark-to-maturity, which allows us to cast performance
evaluation in a long-horizon perspective.
2.3. Updating Future Pension Assets and the Risk-Return Trade-Off.
Figure 4 allows the investment plan member to understand the implications of realized
performance in a retirement perspective by projecting her assets to age 65, given the actual
performance realized during the first year and her initial asset allocation. Both the red and the
black benchmark appear clearly in Figure 4.
Obviously, a below-mean performance after one year makes it less likely that the plan participant
will reach the "money-back" benchmark (the probability increases to 3.80%, up from 3.35%, and
the average shortfall increases from €5361 to €5446, as stated in Table III 4 ). But mean
accumulated assets are equal to € 179,392.88. Note that the mean accumulated assets have
roughly remained the same as in the t=0 example. This indicates that a long time horizon allows
for the possibility of offsetting initial adverse shocks, making it less sensible to deviate from a
pre-determined investment policy. This holds true even in the (unreported) case of a loss of all
initial contributions: the probability of ending below the benchmark increases to 4.3%, the
average shortfall jumps as high as €8006 and average accumulated assets fall slightly to
€175,075.
4
Section 2 assumes that realized wage growth and realized inflation are both equal
expectations. This is indeed the simplest case.
6
to 0%, in line with
By comparison, consider a member that starts contributing two years from retirement. At the
beginning she expects as cumulated assets equal to €2,522, against a benchmark capital of
€2,400. The probability of ending below the benchmark is high (36%) with an average shortfall
of €178. After all of the contributions are lost in the first year, the average accumulated assets fall
to €1,228, well below the benchmark, the probability of not reaching the target jumps to 100%
and the average shortfall is equal to €1172.
3. Reporting Monthly Pension Equivalent of Accumulated Asset.
Our previous framework reports the projected amount of accumulated and capitalized
contributions at retirement. This does not clearly inform beneficiaries on consumption
possibilities, which is a central demand of plan members. This information is better conveyed by
the replacement rate -- i.e. the ratio of the annual pension annuity to wage.5 But replacement
ratios are less clearly associated with fund performance and their determination is not
straightforward in a DC world. Our proposal, which aims at easing long-term performance
evaluation, thus focuses primarily on the projected amount of contributions.
However, we do engage in the further step that consists of converting accumulated capital at
retirement in a monthly pension pay. This exercise allows to highlight another relevant
dimension of risk. The monthly pension pay will depend on the conversion rate between the
capital at retirement and annuities, which in turn will be a function of a set of factors such as
interest rates, mortality, transaction costs, fees, and so forth. In section 3.1. we also contrast the
projected pension annuity/ drawdown profile with a desired pension payment, computed as a
percentage of the current wage (i.e. a component of a replacement rate at retirement) 6. This
kind of reporting, based on further assumptions concerning the length of life after retirement,
allows the pension member to assess the income/consumption possibilities, and their variability
as a function of the interest rate that will prevail at retirement.
Appendix A1 takes an additional step, by explicitly modeling stochastic interest rates in order to
show that particular kinds of asset allocation are able to contain the variability of consumption
in response to interest rate shocks. Pension members who either must annuitize or choose to do
so, may prefer a portfolio at retirement that is “conformable” with the annuities pay-out.
Appendix A1 provides three reporting examples based on alternative asset allocations that
differently immunize prospective annuities from interest rate volatility.
3.1.Communicating Monthly Pension Equivalent of Accumulated Assets
In this section we translate the results portrayed in Figure 2, which are expressed in terms of total
accumulated assets, into annuities (i.e. into an equivalent monthly pay received after retirement).
This kind of reporting best suits those systems that partially or fully annuitize DC pension
5
Pension authorities use replacement ratios in order to communicate pension adequacy – for instance, in the
Swedish “orange envelope”. See also the Chilean pension simulator that projects DC pension benefits at
retirement (Berstein et al, 2013).
6
It is also possible to highlight an alternative “annuities benchmark”. This is the conversion of the “real moneyback” capital in an annuity, given an expected real interest rate and given the expected age of retirement. This
benchmark is thus directly comparable with current wage.
7
benefits. Even for systems where annuities are not mandatory, this reporting method makes it
possible to have a representation of the expected replacement rate of a DC plan in terms of
current wages.
In the examples that follow we will assume a life expectancy of 20 years post-retirement. 7
Moreover, we allow for 10 possible levels of conversion rates at retirement, which we use to
convert real accumulated capital into a monthly real annuity. Conversion rates depend essentially
on life expectancy and real interest rates. In our examples, life expectancy is fixed; thus, the
variability of conversion rates depends on possible alternative real interest rates. We therefore
convert each of the 2,000 simulated levels of accumulated capital above, using alternative interest
rates. We start with a 1% real interest rate, and we average the 2,000 possible pays to achieve a
monthly average pay of € 816.40. And we repeat this exercise for the other possible interest rates.
Table IV shows all the results of the average monthly pension during retirement. It ranges from
€816.40 when the interest rate is as low as 1%, to € 1,663.44 for a high level of the interest rateclearly displaying the sensitivity of pension income to the rate. The columns of table IV show the
average monthly pay. We now see that the average pension would not be sufficient to match the
desired income in some interest rate environments. Unless another source of pension wage is
present, a participant may therefore want to increase her contribution.
Communication can be further improved by highlighting the desired monthly pension as a
percentage of the current wage. Figure 5 also displays the average “+ 1 standard deviation” and
the average “- 1 standard deviation” pension, respectively labeled better and worse. The grey line
in the figure shows the desired monthly pension per month, set at Euro € 875,00.8 The graph now
makes clear that only better return scenarios allow the investor participant to hit the desired
replacement rate when interest rate is low. As in Figure 2, the black line indicates the real moneyback benchmark, converted into monthly annuity payments, which rises with higher real interest
rates. A conservative participant may even want to limit the projected gap between the two lines
by raising monthly contributions during the accumulation phase.
A problem with these representations is that the pension fund, which is responsible for the reports
we are addressing, may not be able to control the terms of annuity provision. A second difficulty
is that inflation protected annuities, like the ones portrayed in Table IV and Figure 5, are very
seldom marketed by insurance companies.
4. Pension Fund Reporting, Inflation and Real Wage Growth.
Sections 2 and 3 assume that realized wage growth and realized inflation are both equal to 0%, in
line with expectations. This is the simplest possible case, but hides three issues.
First, realizations typically differ from expectations. Over time, such differences may become so
large as to make projections no longer meaningful for the plan member. We suggest that such
7
Users of this reporting scheme may refer to mortality tables (conditional on country, age, sex …) to get better
estimates.
8
In the Netherlands, the most common wage (modus) is about € 35,000 a year. If we take 30% of this wage
(which roughly accounts for the Dutch second-pillar part of retirement pay) and divide by 12 we get € 875.00.
8
realizations be incorporated in the projection updates (as in Figure 4) every year. Appendix B
provides an example with positive realized wage growth, where contributions increase with real
wages. It also allows for positive realized inflation. In order to make the projected pension pay
bear a clear link to current pay, it is better to change the base year every year – rather than
leaving it unchanged at t=0.
Second, a pension plan may use alternative expected wage growth or inflation scenarios. An
alternative inflation scenario is irrelevant as long as inflation is non-stochastic (see the example
in section 4.1. below). On the contrary, positive wage growth scenarios imply growing
contributions, which increase benchmark capital at retirement. Alternative wage growth
scenarios can thus be used, but they should always be compared to the conservative default
option of zero expected growth.
Last but not least, previous sections assume non-stochastic inflation – or, that inflation risk can
be fully hedged at no cost. Such costs, when present, ought instead to be deducted from return
projections. Moreover, projections understate the risk of asset allocations that are tilted towards
imperfect inflation hedges such as long-term nominal bonds. Section 4.2 indicates the way to
explicitly embed stochastic inflation into our reporting framework. We postpone until section
5.2 a discussion about stochastic wage growth.
4.1. Non-Stochastic Inflation
Assume that the expected inflation rate is equal to 2% (ECB benchmark). If the inflation rate is
non-stochastic, then it is perfectly anticipated. It follows that nominal returns on assets are equal
to 7.5% for stocks and 4.5% for bonds, respectively with no change in real returns, volatility and
correlation. The yearly nominal return, ensuring that the value of pension assets will be equal to
the benchmark at retirement, is equal to 2.44%. With these changes, the average, maximum and
minimum returns on accumulated assets roughly coincide with the ones described above, without
inflation.
4.2. Stochastic Inflation
Let us now assume that the inflation rate has non-zero volatility. This is going to increase
(reduce) the expected real return on assets that are good (bad) inflation hedges, thus changing the
range of possible outcomes at retirement in Figure 2. One way to account for this is to estimate a
forecasting model where the distribution of asset returns is a function of the inflation rate, as in
Campbell, Sunderam and Viceira (2013) or more simply in Briére et al. (2011) and Fugazza,
Guidolin and Nicodano (2010). The reporting scheme should not otherwise be affected by
stochastic inflation. Even if realized inflation differs from what had been expected, both ex post
performance and revised projections are a function of real variables only. A higher-thanexpected inflation will depress the realized real return on pension assets below the expected
outcomes, if these assets are not good inflation hedges; and will require higher nominal
contributions in order to keep projected contributions constant in real terms.
9
5. Discussion
Our framework provides an example of a reporting standard based on relatively straightforward
calculation rules that can be performed by pension plans and understood by plan members.
While the reporting standard should be based on common scenarios and layouts to ease
comparisons, the underlying framework lends itself to other uses. It can accommodate alternative
communication frameworks (future pension assets or monthly pension equivalent) and inflation
and growth scenarios. It is also possible to simulate the consequences of competing choices by
the plan member, thus contributing to financial education. For instance, a worker may ask to have
her exposure to the stock market reduced after negative performance, such as the one portrayed
in Figure 3. This framework can produce new projections associated with a more defensive asset
allocation, revealing that lower risk entails lower upside potential.
Sections 5.1-5.4 discuss our choices against alternatives that imply substantial departures from
the current simple settings.
5.1. An alternative benchmark
The purchasing power of a future pension is what matters to a prospective retiree. Along these
lines, Bodie and Treussard (2007) assume that contributions are invested in a maturity matched
inflation-indexed bond at time 0, whose principal value is indexed to the CPI and pays,
additionally, a coupon. This way, it is possible to get rid of all (but insolvency) risks. They also
suggest using IIB as a performance benchmark.
We could adopt the same approach.9 We opt instead for a benchmark with zero real return, which
is compared with a net-of-fee return on pension assets under management. The rationale behind
this proposal is the following. First, a CPI benchmark is easy to understand and communicate.
Second, this benchmark has the desirable property of being achievable in normal circumstances
of positive real interest rates, at least where there is a market for IIB, and also given that equities
have historically provided positive real returns over longer periods.10 Third, attaining the CPI
benchmark, while possible, is not straightforward. Markets for inflation-linked bonds are absent
in some countries. Even where they exist, there may be discontinuity in the coverage of the yield
curve, so that inflation cannot be hedged at all horizons without bearing some market risk11.
Furthermore, covering inflation plus management costs remains a challenge in itself, especially
when the time-to-retirement is short.
The solution we propose here, besides being driven by a search for simplicity, may be able to
satisfy the various parties involved: the investors, who would receive a standardized
representation of retirement capital in real terms; the industry, which may be willing to adopt this
9
In our framework, some real interest rate risk would still be present because contributions are invested
throughout the life cycle (not just at t=0), and the rate on IIB that prevails in the future is unknown.
10
On the contrary, efficient benchmarks (with no transaction costs and no fees) on average beat the performance
of net-of-fee asset managers by definition, thus generating misunderstandings with investors. Inefficient
benchmarks such as stock indexes may be hard to beat in practice because of regulatory restrictions that prevent
managers from investing outside the benchmark asset menu.
11
A similar observation motivates the investigation by Martellini and Milhau (2013).
10
reporting standard because it is offered an attainable benchmark; and the regulators, because this
is consistent with investor protection principles.
5.2. A life-cycle approach
There are several ways in which the model could benefit from life-cycle research. On the one
hand, it may help design the contribution path. In our model, contributions grow together with
the realized wage growth. However, a welfare-enhancing contribution profile connects
contributions to the plan member's income and family composition, in such a way that
contributions constrain less the consumption of young families and weigh more on older and
richer families. 12
Life-cycle research also recognizes that an investor's total wealth, and the risk she bears is
derived not only from financial returns but from labor income as well. In certain countries, labor
income gives rise to pension wealth in the form of first-pillar entitlements. Ideally, then, Figures
2, 3 and 4 ought to portray the possible values of total accumulated assets, which may include
also first-pillar entitlements. To the extent that such financial and labor incomes are not perfectly
correlated, bad (good) financial shocks are compensated by good (bad) labor income shocks. This
reasoning implies that the variability of total accumulated assets is likely to be smaller than that
of pension fund assets only. Our proposal sidesteps this approach, in order to focus more closely
on rolling performance assessment which requires focusing on the financial wealth generated by
the pension plan.13
5.3. Return predictability and rebalancing of contributions
Our assumption of independent returns over time has several implications. On the one hand, it
implies that future returns cannot be predicted on the basis of past realized returns, or past
realized inflation, and so forth. Moreover, our assumption implies that there is no gain from
active portfolio management. Finally, the annualized conditional variance of returns is
independent of the investor’s horizon.
There is, however, a large literature on return predictability, which shows that lagged returns, the
inflation rate, the dividend-price ratio, the term premium and the default premium can explain
current equity, real estate, bond and especially T-bill returns in in-sample experiments.
Predictability impacts on optimal portfolio management, creating a difference between longterm and short-term management. Indeed, if returns on equities (bonds) are mean reverting
(averting), then the equity (bond) annualized volatility over a long horizon is lower (higher) than
the annualized volatility over a short horizon. An optimal long-run portfolio entails a higher
12
Research on optimal life-cycle investments (among others see Benzoni et al., 2007; Bodie et al. (1992, 2009);
Campbell et al., 2001; Cocco et al., 2005; and Koijen et al, 2010 and Bagliano et al., 2014) provides the logical
background for consumption-smoothing contribution paths that are able to improve on the investor's welfare.
13
However, the performance evaluation for pension plans may also be based on their ability to smooth
consumption during retirement years (see Bagliano et al., 2010).
11
(lower) equity (bond) share than a short-term one does (Campbell and Viceira, 2005; Fugazza,
Guidolin and Nicodano, 2007). However, there is no consensus, yet, as to whether these patterns
are useful for improving future portfolio performance relative to simpler strategies (Goyal and
Welch, 2008; Fugazza, Guidolin and Nicodano, 2014; Turner, 2014), or whether it is necessary to
resort to more elaborate prediction models. This is why we stick to the simplest return
representation which can, however, be changed without prejudice to the rest of the proposal.
Our projections also keep the yearly contribution insensitive to realized returns. The projections
could instead allow for increases in contributions after lower than-expected returns14. In this case,
this feature should be incorporated also when building the ex ante accumulated assets
projections. This dynamic "contribution rebalancing" strategy would yield better outcomes if
portfolio returns were negatively correlated over time at the yearly frequency.
5.4. Parameter uncertainty and forecast reliability
Our framework assumes that forecasts of outcome ranges are reliable because the distribution of
asset returns is known. On the contrary, the parameters (mean, variance, etc) of the assumed
distribution are usually estimated from the data with errors. The latter affect comparatively more
riskier than safer assets, and compound over time reducing the precision of long-term forecasts of
riskier assets. In turn, this implies that long term risk-averse investors are less attracted by riskier
assets relative to short-term investors because of this added uncertainty (see Barberis, 2000;
Fugazza, Guidolin and Nicodano, 2009). Our reporting framework omits the modeling of such
estimation error, thus implicitly understating the risk of riskier assets the more so, the longer the
horizon. More generally, we do not provide any hint as to the reliability of the forecast.
5.5. Outsourcing return forecasts used in projections?
Projections rely on the distribution of returns on several asset classes. In our proposal, these are
chosen by each pension fund on the grounds that each could have views on asset prospects that
motivate their proposed asset allocation. At the same time, incentives to boost returns in order to
attract new members should be mitigated by the knowledge that disappointed members are
likelier to leave the fund ex post. This mitigation may not work if managers have short horizons
and there are short-term performance fees. In such a case the industry association may provide
return forecasts to all pension funds. This also preserves comparability of performance across
pension funds.
6. Concluding comments
DC pension funds currently project expected benefits at retirement in a very limited set of
countries, using either no risk scenario or a very limited number of scenarios –but for the case of
Chile. Our reporting framework projects the distribution of outcomes at retirement associated
with a large number of scenarios, thus making the plan member aware of both the upside
14
Besides, during periods of dramatic declines in equities prices, participants may not be willing to increase
contributions fearing for the continuation of their jobs.
12
potential and the downside risk. This is in line with the desire of supervisory authorities, which
are not only aware of the importance of projections, but also stress the need to convey to plan
members the level of uncertainty surrounding expected benefits (OECD, 2010b; Rinaldi, and
Giacomel, 2008).
Another concern of the authorities has to do with the conflict of interest between fund members
and pension providers, exacerbated by the poor understanding of the impact of cost and fees
(Rinaldi and Giacomel, 2008). We address this problem as follows. First, we propose associating
projections with the asset allocation chosen by the plan member, so as to make her aware of the
higher risks associated with larger equity investments. Second, the plan member is able to assess
ex-post pension fund performance against the latter previous projections, so as to curb the
incentives to overstate future returns and pension benefits. Third, the return on the money-backbenchmark is cost-free, thus implicitly putting an upper bound on charges. Thus the plan member
can grasp the additional costs and downside risks of alternatives to the "money-back" benchmark
at retirement. At the same time, this reporting framework has advantages for the industry as well,
especially in terms of fair comparability with the benchmark and simple and effective
communication. Indeed, the plan member also understands the costs of lower risk strategies in
terms of foregone upside potential. Secondly, reports do not emphasize poor ex-post pension plan
performance until the real return, net of costs, falls below zero. Finally, a longer-term assessment
may mitigate the pension member’s reaction to poor short-term performance, which often results
in withdrawals in bear markets.
A final concern of regulators has to do with the actual framing of reports so as to ensure they are
understood by plan members (OECD, 2010b). While this proposal does not address this issue in
detail, we wish to stress that we limit the amount of information, knowing that too much
information is equivalent to none. Indeed, we envisage the regular distribution of only two
figures and tables with explanatory notes to all members. A website should contain information
on assumptions, on the chosen asset allocation as well as disclaimers. More work on this aspect is
postponed to future drafts.
REFERENCES
Antolin, P. and O. Fuentes (2012), Communicating pension risk to dc plan members: the Chilean
case of a pension risk simulator, OECD Working papers on finance, insurance and private
pensions, 28, Paris, 2012
Antolín, P. and D. Harrison (2012), Annual DC Pension Statements and the Communications
Challenge, OECD: Working Papers on Finance, Insurance and Private Pensions,19
Antolin, P. R. Hinz, H. P. Rudolph and J. Yermo, eds. (2010) Evaluating the Financial
Performance of Pension Funds, The World Bank; Washington.
Bagliano, F.C., C. Fugazza and G. Nicodano (2010) Pension Funds, Life-Cycle, Asset Allocation
and Performance Evaluation, in Antolin et al. eds., p.159
13
Bagliano, F.C., C. Fugazza and G. Nicodano (2014) Optimal Life-cycle Portfolios for
Heterogeneous Workers, Review of Finance, 18 (6): 2283-2323
Benzoni, L., P. Collin-Dufresne and R.G. Goldstein (2007) Portfolio Choice over the Life-Cycle
when the Stock and Labor Markets are Cointegrated, Journal of Finance, 62, 5, 2123-2167.
Berstein, S., O. Fuentes and F. Villatoro (2013), Default investment strategies in a defined
contribution pension system: a pension risk model application for the Chilean case, Journal of
Pension Economics and Finance, 379-414
Blake D., D. Lehmann and A. Timmerman (1999) Asset Allocation Dynamics and Pension Fund
Performance, Journal of Business, 72.
Bodie, Z., Detemple J. and M. Rindisbacher (2009) Life Cycle. Finance and the Design of
Pension Plans, Annual Review of Financial Economics, 1, 249-286.
Bodie Z., R.C. Merton and W. Samuelson (1992) Labor Supply Flexibility and Portfolio Choice
in a Life Cycle Model, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 16, 427-449.
Bodie, Z. and J. Treussard (2007) Making Investment Choices as Simple as Possible: An
Analysis of Target Date Retirement Funds, ssrn.com.
Brière, M. and O. Signori (2012) Inflation-hedging Portfolios: Economic Regimes Matter, The
Journal of Portfolio Management, 38(5), 43-58.
Campbell, J.Y, A. Sunderam, and M.L. Viceira (2013) Inflation Bets or Deflation Hedges? The
Changing Risks of Nominal Bonds, Harvard University.
Campbell,J.Y., J. Cocco, F. Gomes and P. Maenhout (2001) Investing Retirement Wealth: A
Life-Cycle Model, in Campbell J.Y. and M. Feldstein (eds.), Risk Aspects of Investment-Based
Social Security Reform, University of Chicago Press.
Campbell J.Y. and L. M. Viceira (2001) Who Should Buy Long-Term Bonds?, American
Economic Review 91:99-127.
Campbell J.Y. and L. Viceira (2005) The Term Structure of the Risk-Return Tradeoff,
Financial Analyst Journal, 61(1), 2005, 34-44
Campbell J.Y. and L.M. Viceira, Strategic Asset Allocation. Oxford Univesity Press, 2002.
Cocco, J., F. Gomes and P. Maenhout (2005) Consumption and Portfolio Choice over the Life
Cycle, Review of Financial Studies, 18, 491-533.
14
Coggin, T.D., F. J. Fabozzi and S. Rahaman (1993) The Investment Performance of U.S. Equity
Pension Fund Managers: An Empirical Investigation, The Journal of Finance, Vol. 48, No. 3,
1039-1055.
Del Guercio, D. and P.A. Tkac (2008) Star Power: The Effect of Morningstar Ratings on Mutual
Fund Flow, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 43: 907-936 .
Del Guercio, D. and P.A. Tkac (2002) The Determinants of the Flow of Funds of Managed
Portfolios: Mutual Funds vs. Pension Funds, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis,
37(4), 523-557.
DeMiguel, V., L. Garlappi and R. Uppal (2008) Optimal versus Naive Diversification: How
Inefficient is the 1/N Portfolio Strategy?, Review of Financial Studies.
Elton, E.J, M.J. Gruber and C. R. Blake (2007) Participant Reaction and the Performance of
Funds Offered by 401(k) Plans, Journal of Financial Intermediation. 16(2), 240-271.
Friesen, G.C. and T.R.A. Sapp, Mutual Fund Flows and Investor Returns: An Empirical
Examination of Fund Investor Timing Ability, Journal of Banking & Finance 31, 9, 2007, 27962816.
Fugazza, C., M. Guidolin and G. Nicodano (2007) Investing for the Long Run in European Real
Estate, Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 2007, 34(1), 35-80.
Fugazza, C., M. Guidolin and G. Nicodano (2009) Time and Risk Diversification in Real Estate
Investments: the Ex-Post Performance, Real Estate Economics, 37(3), 341-381.
Fugazza, C., M. Guidolin and G. Nicodano (2014), Equally Weighted vs. Long-Run Optimal
Portfolios, European Financial Management, forthcoming
Global Investment Performance Standards (GIPS) Handbook, Second Edition 2006
Goyal, A. and I. Welch (2008) A Comprehensive Look at the Empirical Performance of Equity
Premium Prediction, Review of Financial Studies, 21 (4): 1453-1454.
Group of Thirty (2013), Long-term Finance and Economic Growth, Working Group on Longterm Finance, Washington, DC.
Ippolito, R.A., and J.A. Turner (1987) Turnover, Fees and Pension Plans Performance, Financial
Analysts Journal, November-December, 16-26.
Koijen, R.S.J, T. Nijman and B.J.M. Werker (2010) When Can Life-Cycle Investors Benefit from
Time-Varying Bond Risk Premia?, Review of Financial Studies, 23 (2).
Lehmann, B. and A. Timmermann (2008) Performance Measurement and Evaluation in A.Boot
and A.Thakor "Handbook of Financial Intermediation and Banking".
15
Martellini, L. and V. Milhau An Empirical Analysis of the Benefits of Inflation-Linked Bonds,
Real Estate and Commodities for Long-Term Investors with Inflation-Linked Liabilities,
Bankers, Markets & Investors, 124, 2013
OECD Working Party on Private Pensions (2010a) COMMUNICATING PROJECTED PENSION
BENEFITS AND RISKS IN DEFINED CONTRIBUTION PENSION PLANS DAF/AS/PEN/WD.
OECD Working Party on Private Pensions (2010b) HUMAN CAPITAL AND PROTECTING DC
RETIREMENT INCOME.
Rakowski, D. and X. Wang (2009) The Dynamics of Short-Term Mutual Fund Flows and
Returns: A time-series and Cross-sectional Investigation, Journal of Banking & Finance, 33,(11),
2102-2109.
Rinaldi A., and E. Giacomel (2008), Information to members of DC Pension Plans: Conceptual
Framework and International Trends, IOPS Working Paper 5
Sirri, E., Tufano, P. (1998), Costly Search and Mutual Fund Flows, Journal of Finance, 53,1589–
162.
Turner, J.A., 2014, Casting doubt on the predictability of stock returns in real time: Bayesian
Model averaging using realistic priors, Review of Finance 18, 1-37.
Viceira L. M. (2010), Pension Fund Design in Developing Economies, in Antolin et al (eds),
203-239
Viceira L. M. (2001) Optimal Portfolio Choice for Long-Horizon Investors with Nontradable
Labor Income, Journal of Finance, 56, 433-470.
Viceira, L. M. (2009) Life-Cycle Funds. In A. Lusardi ed., Overcoming the Saving Slump: How
to Increase the Effectiveness of Financial Education and Saving Programs, University of
Chicago Press.
16
Table I
The Assumptions Underlying Projections
The table reports assumptions concerning the parameters listed in the first column. Percentage
returns and growth rates are annualized. The real returns on equity and bonds are assumed to be
jointly log-normally distributed, and IID over time.
Inflation Rate (π)
Real Returns on 10-year Duration Govt. Bonds
Real Equity Returns
Bond-Equity Return Correlation
Inter-temporal Return Correlation
Yearly Real Wage Growth Rate (w)
Monthly Contribution
Percentage Transaction Costs on New Contributions
Percentage Yearly Fee on Assets Under Management
Rebalancing Costs
Tax rates
Mean
0
Standard Deviation
2.5
3.0
5.5
0.1
0
0
100
0.5
0.4
0
0
18
//
//
0
Figure 1
Asset allocation
This figure explains to the worker the chosen asset allocation and how it evolves during life. In
this example, the allocation entails 20% in bonds and 80% in stocks, with quarterly rebalancing.
Asset allocation through time
100%
90%
80%
70%
60%
50%
40%
30%
20%
10%
0%
25
30
35
40
45
Return assets
50
55
Low risk assets
17
60
Figure 2
Projected pension assets at age 25
This is the figure the worker sees when joining the pension fund at age 25. It reports projected
pension assets from age 25 to age 65, when yearly contributions equal € 1,200. The benchmark
"your money-back", which corresponds to a zero real rate of return, appears in black. Mean
accumulated assets appear in white. The asset allocation entails 20% in bonds and 80% in stocks,
with quarterly rebalancing.
Accumulated assets
250,000
200,000
150,000
100,000
50,000
0
25
30
35
40
45
18
50
55
60
Table II
Key projected outcomes at 25
The first column reports statistics relating to shortfall risk. The first row indicates the probability
of not reaching the "money-back" benchmark after 40 years. The second, fourth and fifth rows
indicate the average, maximum and minimum euro shortfall with respect to the benchmark. The
second column shows the average, maximum and minimum accumulated assets. The last four
rows indicate upper and lower percentile boundary figures for accumulated assets.
Probability
Average
st.dev
Maximum
Minimum
5 % distr. upper bound
1 5% distr. upper bound
15% distr. lower bound
5% distr. lower bound
Risk of not reaching
benchmark after
accumulation phase
3.35%
-6,772.41
5,361.47
-23,299.75
-72.97
Amount of assets
after accumulation
phase (40 years)
177,597.05
137,020.73
1,735,955.07
24,747.04
409,432.80
273,318.78
76,519.86
53,064.12
Figure 3
Realized and projected pension assets at age 26
This figure allows the worker to assess the yearly performance of her pension fund at age 26. It
highlights with a white square mark, the actual ex-post accumulated assets against projected
ones. In the picture both the white and black benchmarks are highlighted.
Accumulated assets after year 1
1,800
1,600
1,400
1,200
1,000
800
600
400
200
0
25
25 1/4
25 1/2
19
25 3/4
Figure 4
Projected retirement assets at age 26
This figure allows a 26-year-old worker to project her assets to age 65, conditional on one-year
actual performance. Both the black and the white benchmark appear clearly.
Accumulated assets
250,000
200,000
150,000
100,000
50,000
0
25
30
35
40
45
50
55
60
Table III
Key projected outcomes at 26.
The first column reports statistics relating to shortfall risk one year later. The first row indicates
the probability of not reaching the "money-back" benchmark after 39 years. The second, fourth
and fifth rows indicate the average, maximum and minimum euro shortfall with respect to the
benchmark. The second column shows the average, maximum and minimum accumulated assets.
The last four rows indicate upper and lower percentile boundary figures for accumulated assets.
Probability
Average
st.dev
Maximum
Minimum
5 % distr. upper bound
1 5% distr. upper bound
15% distr. lower bound
5% distr. lower bound
Risk of not reaching
benchmark after
accumulation phase
3.80%
-7,886.28
5,546.26
-23,820.32
-111.64
20
Amount of assets
after accumulation
phase (39 years)
179,392.88
144,923.19
2,274,260.18
24,221.01
425,976.47
279,918.53
74,447.81
51,211.86
Table IV
The table IV shows all the results of the average monthly pension during retirement. The
columns show the average monthly pay.
Monthly pension equivalent of accumulated capital at retirement.
This table reports the level of the real interest rate at retirement in the first row, and the associated
average monthly pension pay in the second row.
1%
2%
3%
4%
5%
6%
7%
8%
9%
10%
816.40 896.91 981.35 1,069.52 1,161.19 1,256.13 1,354.08 1,454.79 1,557.99 1,663.44
Figure 5
Simulated and desired pension payments, deterministic interest rates and money-back
benchmark.
This figure reports the level of the real interest rate at retirement on the horizontal axis, and the
monthly pension on the vertical one. The grey line indicates desired monthly pension, the darkest
bars the average monthly pension, the darker and lighter bars a worse and better outcomes
(respectively corresponding to the average minus/plus one standard deviation). In line with
Figure 2, the black line indicates the real money-back benchmark, converted into monthly
annuity payments, which rises with higher real interest rates. The grey line in the figure below
shows the desired monthly pension per month, set at Euro € 875,00.
Payments, interest rates and replacement rates
5,000.00
4,500.00
4,000.00
3,500.00
3,000.00
2,500.00
2,000.00
1,500.00
1,000.00
500.00
0.00
1%
2%
Worse
3%
Average
4%
5%
Better
21
6%
7%
Target monthly annuity
8%
9%
10%
Real money back
Appendix A
A.1. Stochastic interest rates.
In Figure 5 we assumes ten exogenous interest rate levels. Of course, interest rates are not
equally likely. Moreover, one should also account for the impact of realized interest rates on
bond values. When these features are built in the model, projections reveal the effects of
alternative asset allocations on pension payment sensitivity to the interest rate. Below we show
the effects of a , one which gradually invests in long-term bonds over the accumulation phase,
Figure A1
Projected pension assets at age 25 with stochastic interest rate
This figure is the counterpart of Figure 2, when the interest rate is simulated instead of the bond
return. It reports projected pension assets from age 25 to age 65, when yearly contributions equal
€ 1,200. The money-back benchmark appears in black. Mean accumulated assets appear in white.
The asset allocation entails 20% in bonds and 80% in stocks, with quarterly rebalancing.
Accumulated assets
250,000
200,000
150,000
100,000
50,000
0
25
30
35
40
45
22
50
55
60
Table A1
Key projected outcomes at age 25 with stochastic interest rate
This table is the counterpart of Table II, when the interest rate is simulated instead of the bond
return. The first column reports statistics relating to shortfall risk. The first row indicates the
probability of not reaching the "money-back" benchmark after 40 years. The second, fourth and
fifth rows indicate the average, maximum and minimum euro shortfall with respect to the
benchmark. The second column shows the average, maximum and minimum accumulated assets.
The last four rows indicate upper and lower percentile boundary figures for accumulated assets.
Probability
Average
st.dev
Maximum
Minimum
5 % distr. upper bound
1 5% distr. upper bound
15% distr. lower bound
5% distr. lower bound
Risk of not reaching
benchmark after
accumulation phase
3.35%
-7,212.73
5,261.22
-23,432.69
-58.02
23
Amount of assets
after accumulation
phase (40 years)
181,531.67
133,676.06
1,524,056.49
24,614.10
430,144.39
287,072.19
77,008.42
52,425.33
Figure A2
Simulated and desired pension payments, stochastic interest rates
and money-back benchmark.
This figure is the counterpart of Figure 5, when the interest rate is simulated instead of the bond
return. It shows the level of the real interest rate at retirement on the horizontal axis, and the
monthly pension on the vertical one. The grey line indicates desired monthly pension, the dots
the simulated monthly pension payments. The black line indicates the real money-back annuity
benchmark. The asset allocation entails 20% in bonds and 80% in stocks, with quarterly
rebalancing.
10,000.00
9,000.00
8,000.00
7,000.00
6,000.00
5,000.00
4,000.00
3,000.00
2,000.00
1,000.00
-6.00%
-4.00%
-2.00%
0.00%
80/20 Allocation
2.00%
4.00%
Target monthly annuity
6.00%
8.00%
10.00%
12.00%
Real money-back target
In other terms, the pension provider may want to immunize prospective annuities from interest
rates shocks, by “locking in” the portfolio prospective capitals needed for annuity payments. This
can be done with bonds of similar maturity as annuity payments. But before getting into effective
examples of immunization, we would like to analyze the impact of interest rate volatility.
To this end, we repeat the exercise we performed in the main body of the paper, simulating the
real interest rate on five-year duration bonds rather than the return on bonds. The interest rate
distribution is assumed to be lognormal with constant mean of 2.2% and volatility of 1%. The
correlation between equity returns and interest rates is assumed to be low in absolute value and
negative (-0.1). Figure A1 and Table A1 are a fairly close replication of Figure 2 and Table II,
24
based on interest rate instead of bond total return simulation. Figure A2 portrays instead the
simulated pension wage scenarios against realized interest rates. Now we see that higher interest
rate scenarios are less likely than intermediate ones, and cases of negative real rates appear. In
comparison to Figure 5, it reveals that most scenarios end up below benchmark even at
intermediate rates of 4%-5%, and that some high average payments in Figure 5 may actually be
associated with outliers.
Importantly, the simulation of interest rates makes it possible to investigate whether alternative
asset allocations better hedge interest rate risk at retirement, while still beating the benchmark.
For instance, we may wonder whether an equity glide path, which progressively substitutes
constant duration bonds to stocks, is a better hedge against interest rate variation.
Figure A3 portrays the glide path. Figure A4 shows that the glide path substantially reduces very
high and very low outcomes for accumulated assets, which is mirrored in a reduction in both
shortfall probability and average accumulated assets. The following Figure A5 highlights that the
glide path does not really help in shrinking interest rate sensitivity of pension income.
To complete our investigation, we experiment with a20% equity, 80% five-year duration bonds
allocation. Asset projections (see Figure A6) now reveal that shortfall risk is eliminated together
with the upside potential. The impact on monthly pension payment is dramatic. Interest rate risk
is hedged quite well, as the sensitivity of the monthly pension payment is very low. However the
level of the pension payment is almost always below the desired pension payment. Thus, a clear
trade-off emerges between reduced exposure to interest rates and upside potential.
The choice of asset allocation depends on the choice of pension associates and provider.
However, our reporting framework allows us to choose a "conformable" accumulation solution as
a function of the nature of decumulation (fully annuitized, partly annuitized, based on capital
drawdowns) and the life expectancy at retirement. Plan members that are forced to 100%
annuitization will be more inclined to favor hedging of interest rate risk rather than trying to beat
the benchmark.
25
FigureA3
Asset allocation through time
100%
90%
80%
70%
60%
50%
40%
30%
20%
10%
0%
25
30
35
40
45
Return assets
50
55
60
Duration matching assets
Figure A4
Projected pension assets at age 25
This figure is the counterpart of Figure A1, when the asset allocation entails a gradual reduction
of the equity share from age 45 onwards, as represented in Figure A3. It reports projected
pension assets from age 25 to age 65, when yearly contributions equal € 1,200. The money-back
benchmark appears in black. Mean accumulated assets appear in white.
Accumulated assets
250,000
200,000
150,000
100,000
50,000
0
25
30
35
40
45
26
50
55
60
Table A2
Key projected outcomes at age 25
This table is the counterpart of Table A1, when the asset allocation entails a glide path, as
indicated in Figure A3.
Risk of not reaching
benchmark after
accumulation phase
Probability
Average
st.dev
Maximum
Minimum
5 % distr. upper bound
15% distr. upper bound
15% distr. lower bound
5% distr. lower bound
Amount of assets
after accumulation
phase (40 years)
1.75%
-5,190.38
3,679.39
-16,320.79
-702.63
146,581.34
97,302.15
1,217,730.29
31,726.00
327,911.80
212,211.74
74,520.50
59,545.56
A.2. Conformable portfolios
This section provides other examples of portfolios that immunize, in varying degrees, the
participant from interest rate volatility in the accumulation phase. The pension member, with the
help of these projections, can choose the portfolio that best fits her needs of immunizing
prospective annuities from interest rate volatility.
A.2.1. 100% matching annuities with bonds immunization in the accumulation phase
In this first example, contributions are invested in zero coupon bonds or swaps of decreasing
maturity so as to provide 100% matching– as indicated in Figure A5. In Figure A6, the black line
indicates the money-back (€ 48,000 in this case) benchmark. The dots form an almost flat line,
indicating that the interest rate sensitivity of the monthly pension payment is minimal. It is
apparent that the dots are always below the money-back benchmark in black. Thus, the
benchmark appears unattainable with this asset allocation, since there are no equities and
therefore no benefit from the equity risk premium. This is equally evident in Table A3, which
reports statistics concerning accumulated assets at retirement. The probability of not reaching the
benchmark is 1.
27
Figure A5
Asset allocation through time
100%
90%
80%
70%
60%
50%
40%
30%
20%
10%
0%
25
30
35
40
45
50
55
60
Return assets
Zero coupon 10y
Zero coupon 15y
Zero coupon 20y
Zero coupon 25y
Zero coupon 30y
Zero coupon 35y
Zero coupon 40y
28
Figure A6
Simulated and desired pension payments, stochastic interest rates
and money-back benchmark.
This figure is the counterpart of Figure A2, with stochastic interest rate, when the asset allocation
entails 100% maturity matching, as indicated in Figure A5.
5,000.00
4,500.00
4,000.00
3,500.00
3,000.00
2,500.00
2,000.00
1,500.00
1,000.00
500.00
-8.00%
-6.00%
-4.00%
-2.00%
Cash Flow Matching
0.00%
2.00%
Target monthly annuity
4.00%
6.00%
Real money-back target
8.00%
10.00%
Table A3
Key projected outcomes at age 25
This table is the counterpart of Table A1, when the asset allocation entails 100% maturity matching, as
indicated in Figure A5.
Probability
Average
st.dev
Maximum
Minimum
5 % distr. upper bound
15% distr. upper bound
15% distr. lower bound
5% distr. lower bound
Risk of not reaching
target after acc.
Phase
100.00%
-12,322.52
3,072.01
-20,366.60
-154.35
29
Amount of assets
after accumulation
phase (40 years)
35,724.27
3,072.01
47,892.44
27,680.19
41,074.68
38,913.79
32,540.92
30,889.37
A.2.2. Constant 20% equity exposure and bonds immunization during accumulation.
In this second example, 20% of the portfolio is invested in equities, so as to take advantage of
the risk premium, while the rest provides immunization from interest rate volatility (see Figure
A7). Figure A8 shows that expected pension payments are now more sensitive to the interest
rate, but it is more likely that the money-back benchmark is attained thanks to partial equity
exposure.
Figure A7
Asset allocation through time
100%
90%
80%
70%
60%
50%
40%
30%
20%
10%
0%
25
30
35
40
45
50
55
60
Return assets
Zero coupon 10y
Zero coupon 15y
Zero coupon 20y
Zero coupon 25y
Zero coupon 30y
Zero coupon 35y
Zero coupon 40y
30
Figure A8
Simulated and desired pension payments, stochastic interest rates and money-back benchmark.
This figure is the counterpart of Figure A6 when the asset allocation is the one depicted in
Figure A7. Note the different scale on the vertical axis.
1,000.00
900.00
800.00
700.00
600.00
500.00
400.00
300.00
200.00
100.00
-8.00%
-6.00%
-4.00%
-2.00%
0.00%
20% return assets 80% matching
2.00%
4.00%
Target monthly annuity
31
6.00%
8.00%
Real money-back target
10.00%
A.2.3.Dynamic optimization with equities and bonds immunization during accumulation
In this last example the exposure to equities is much higher and portfolio immunization with
respect to expected annuities starts later, at age 45. The equity risk premium allows the
participant to have higher expected returns but of course implies a broader risk cone. An
alternative representation of Figure A10 below, which echoes Figure 5, is given in Figure A11.
Figure A9 Dynamic glide path
Asset allocation through time
100%
90%
80%
70%
60%
50%
40%
30%
20%
10%
0%
25
30
35
40
45
50
Return assets
Zero coupon 10y
Zero coupon 20y
Zero coupon 25y
32
55
60
Zero coupon 15y
Figure A10
Simulated and desired pension payments, stochastic interest rates and money-back benchmark.
This figure is the counterpart of Figure A6 when the asset allocation is the glide path depicted
in Figure A9.
10,000.00
9,000.00
8,000.00
7,000.00
6,000.00
5,000.00
4,000.00
3,000.00
2,000.00
1,000.00
-8.00%
-6.00%
-4.00%
-2.00%
0.00%
2.00%
4.00%
6.00%
8.00%
10.00%
Glide path with matching investments
Target monthly annuity
Real money-back target
33
Figure A11
Simulated and desired pension payments, stochastic interest rates and money-back benchmark
This figure is the counterpart of Figure 5, when the real interest rate is stochastic. The real
interest rate at retirement is on the horizontal axis, and the monthly pension on the vertical one.
The asset allocation is the glide path depicted in Figure A9.
Payments, interest rates and replacement rates
5,000.00
4,500.00
4,000.00
3,500.00
3,000.00
2,500.00
2,000.00
1,500.00
1,000.00
500.00
0.00
1%
2%
Worse
3%
Average
4%
5%
Better
6%
7%
Target monthly annuity
34
8%
9%
10%
Real money-back target
Appendix B
Communicating Projections and Performance Results in Current Euros
The hypothesis of zero real wage growth is not a necessary component of our model.15 We now
assume a 2% real wage growth forecast for the next 40 years, which sets the money-back
benchmark at € 73,023.75.
Table B1
Contribution per month per person invested
Percentage Real Wage growth per year
Investment horizon
Benchmark capital, in t=0 Euro
Pay-out time annuity
Real Return low-risk assets
Real Risk low-risk assets
Real Return high-return assets
Risk high-return assets
Correlation
Asset allocation low-risk assets
Asset allocation high-return assets
Start capital (t=0)
100.00
2.00%
40 year
73,023.75
20 year
2.5%
3.0%
5.5%
18.0%
10%
20%
80%
0.00
Of course the model can also be run with alternative hypotheses. What matters is to (a) keep the
same scenario as in the previous year, when evaluating ex post performance (b), revising the
inputs for the new projections, on the basis of realized inflation and wage growth. 10 We use a
negative real wage growth case in the next section, where we address the issue of the effect of
inflation on “re-basing” the projections from one year to the next.
B.1. Rebasing projections year after year and the effect of inflation
Reports expressed in terms of constant purchasing power may no longer bear a correspondence
with current purchasing power of plan members after some years, in inflationary scenarios. This
15
The industry association that promotes the reporting standard among its members may
choose the institution providing the inflation and wage forecasts, as well as the ex post figures,
to all pension funds. A personalized pension simulator, such as the Chilean one, may also
deliver individual wage forecast along the lines of Cocco et al. (2005).
35
section explains how to change the base year so as to report in current euro, accounting for nonneutral inflation effects.
Suppose CPI inflation, between t=0 and t=1, equaled 3.0%. That means that our original
benchmark capital should be raised to € 73,023.75 x 1.03 = € 75,214.46 in order to keep the real
benchmark constant. If inflation had been anticipated so that nominal returns were 3% higher
than the real one; and if wage inflation had also been equal to 3%, due to indexation, then
contributions as a share of nominal wage will also increase to 103. Thus there would only be
nominal changes.
Realized inflation affects instead real projected outcomes if returns and incomes do not grow
proportionally with inflation, i.e., when contracts are not perfectly indexed and/or inflation is
unexpected.16
For instance, assume nominal wage growth is only 2% instead of 3% between t=0 and t=1. This
implies that real contributions (rebased in year 1) will now be equal to 102.00 per month, unless
the plan member decides to save a higher share of his real income. So the new set of inputs for
the projections, with base year t=1, are the ones in the table below.
Table B2
The table reports the values of the parameters listed in the first column, expressed in t=1 Euro. Figures
that differ from the ones in Table B1 are in bold. Percentage returns and growth rates are annualized. The
real returns on equity and bonds are assumed to be jointly log-normally distributed, and IID over time.
Contribution per month per person invested
Percentage Real Wage growth per year (expected)
Investment horizon
102.00
2.00%
39 year
Benchmark capital, in t=1 Euro with no erosion in year 0
Benchmark capital in t=1 given erosion in year 0
Pay-out time annuity
Real Return low-risk assets
Real Risk low-risk assets
Real Return high-return assets
Risk high-return assets
Correlation
Asset allocation low-risk assets
Asset allocation high-return assets
Start capital (t=1)
75,214.47
73,009.79.
20 year
2.5%
3.0%
5.5%
18.0%
10%
20%
80%
1,195.00
With the inputs stated above, projected accumulated assets at retirement as a result of
contributions, wage growth and investment horizon are equal to € 73,009.79. Therefore the
higher benchmark capital of €75,214.47 (0.1703%) requires a higher return on investments. This
adds to the gross return on investment needed to compensate for yearly AUM fees and
16
This is the case also if the tax system, which relies on nominal income, is progressive. For the sake of
simplicity, we set the tax rate to zero.
36
transaction costs, which become 0.599% from 0.43%. In other words, inflation has reduced the
real value of contributions, and this also raises the risk of not reaching this benchmark, as
displayed in Table B3 below.
Table B3
Probability
Average
st.dev
Maximum
Minimum
5 % distr. upper bound
15% distr. upper bound
15% distr. lower bound
5% distr. lower bound
Risk of not reaching
benchmark after
accumulation phase
3.60%
-13,986.61
10,755.33
-41,852.74
-156.64
Amount of assets
after accumulation
phase (39 years)
249,033.30
185,924.08
2,214,411.14
34,841.41
596,440.68
373,717.35
110,889.78
82,086.59
Notice that the plan member may want to consider raising her monthly contributions in order to
increase the chance of reaching her desired pension wage. If she increases, at t=1, her monthly
contribution to 120, benchmark capital becomes 85,682.99.
Table B4
Probability
Average
st.dev
Maximum
Minimum
5 % distr. upper bound
15% distr. upper bound
15% distr. lower bound
5% distr. lower bound
Risk of not reaching
benchmark after
accumulation phase
3.65%
-14,675.33
11,727.50
-41,270.85
-68.90
37
Amount of assets
after accumulation
phase (39 years)
284,369.41
193,188.74
1,854,148.70
46,122.94
661,641.84
439,363.17
129,111.85
92,575.40
Our papers can be downloaded at:
http://cerp.carloalberto.org/en/publications
CeRP Working Paper Series
N° 143/14
Kees de Vaan
Daniele Fano
Herialt Mens
Giovanna Nicodano
A Reporting Standard for Defined Contribution Pension Plans
N° 142/14
Elisabetta Cagna
Giulio Casuccio
Equally-weighted Risk Contribution Portfolios: an empirical
study using expected shortfall
N° 141/14
Massimo Baldini
Costanza Torricelli
Maria Cesira Urzì Brancati
Family ties: occupational responses to cope with a household
income shock
N° 140/14
Cecilia Boggio
Elsa Fornero
Henriette Prast
Jose Sanders
Seven Ways to Knit Your Portfolio: Is Investor Communication
Neutral?
N° 139/14
Laura Bianchini
Margherita Borella
Cognitive Functioning and Retirement in Europe
N° 138/13
Claudio Morana
Insights on the global macro-finance interface: Structural sources
of risk factors fluctuations and the cross-section of expected
stock returns
N° 137/13
Claudio Morana
New Insights on the US OIS Spreads Term Structure During the
Recent Financial Turmoil
N° 136/13
Anna Lo Prete
Inequality and the finance you know: does economic literacy
matter?
N° 135/13
Rik Dillingh
Henriette Prast
Mariacristina Rossi
Cesira Urzì Brancati
The psychology and economics of reverse mortgage attitudes:
evidence from the Netherlands
N° 134/13
Annamaria Lusardi
Olivia S. Mitchell
The Economic Importance of Financial Literacy: Theory and
Evidence
N° 133/13
Annamaria Lusardi
Pierre-Carl Michaud
Olivia S. Mitchell
Optimal Financial Knowledge and Wealth Inequality
N° 132/13
Riccardo Calcagno
Sonia Falconieri
Competition and dynamics of takeover contests
N° 131/13
Riccardo Calcagno
Maria Cesira Urzì Brancati
Do more financially literate households invest less in housing?
Evidence from Italy
N° 130/12
Maela Giofré
Financial Education, Investor Protection and International
Portfolio Diversification
N° 129/12
Michele Belloni
Rob Alessie
Adriaan Kalwij
Chiara Marinacci
Lifetime Income and Old Age Mortality Risk in Italy over Two
Decades
N° 128/12
Fabio Cesare Bagliano
Claudio Morana
Determinants of US Financial Fragility Conditions
N° 127/12
Mariacristina Rossi
Serena Trucchi
Liquidity Constraints and Labor Supply
N° 126/11
Margherita Borella
Flavia Coda Moscarola
Mariacristina Rossi
(Un)expected retirement and the consumption puzzle
N° 125/11
Carolina Fugazza
Tracking the Italian employees’ TFR over their working life
careers
N° 124/11
Agnese Romiti
Mariacristina Rossi
Should we Retire Earlier in order to Look After our Parents?
The Role of immigrants
N° 123/11
Elsa Fornero
Maria Cristina Rossi
Maria Cesira Urzì Brancati
Explaining why, right or wrong, (Italian) households do not like
reverse mortgages
N° 122/11
Serena Trucchi
How credit markets affect homeownership: an explanation based
on differences between Italian regions
N° 121/11
Elsa Fornero
Chiara Monticone
Serena Trucchi
The effect of financial literacy on mortgage choices
N° 120/11
Giovanni Mastrobuoni
Filippo Taddei
Age Before Beauty? Productivity and Work vs. Seniority
and Early Retirement
N° 119/11
Maarten van Rooij
Annamaria Lusardi
Rob Alessie
Financial Literacy, Retirement Planning, and Household Wealth
N° 118/11
Luca Beltrametti
Matteo Della Valle
Does the implicit pension debt mean anything after all?
N° 117/11
Riccardo Calcagno
Chiara Monticone
Financial Literacy and the Demand for Financial Advice
N° 116/11
Annamaria Lusardi
Daniel Schneider
Peter Tufano
Financially Fragile Households: Evidence and Implications
N° 115/11
Adele Atkinson
Flore-Anne Messy
Assessing financial literacy in 12 countries: an OECD Pilot
Exercise
N° 114/11
Leora Klapper
Georgios A. Panos
Financial Literacy and Retirement Planning in View of a
Growing Youth Demographic: The Russian Case
N° 113/11
Diana Crossan
David Feslier
Roger Hurnard
Financial Literacy and Retirement Planning in New Zealand
N° 112/11
Johan Almenberg
Jenny Säve-Söderbergh
Financial Literacy and Retirement Planning in Sweden
N° 111/11
Elsa Fornero
Chiara Monticone
Financial Literacy and Pension Plan Participation in Italy
N° 110/11
Rob Alessie
Maarten Van Rooij
Annamaria Lusardi
Financial Literacy, Retirement Preparation and Pension
Expectations in the Netherlands
N° 109/11
Tabea Bucher-Koenen
Annamaria Lusardi
Financial Literacy and Retirement Planning in Germany
N° 108/11
Shizuka Sekita
Financial Literacy and Retirement Planning in Japan
N° 107/11
Annamaria Lusardi
Olivia S. Mitchell
Financial Literacy and Retirement Planning in the United States
N° 106/11
Annamaria Lusardi
Olivia S. Mitchell
Financial Literacy Around the World: An Overview
N° 105/11
Agnese Romiti
Immigrants-Natives Complementarities in Production: Evidence
from Italy
N° 104/11
Ambrogio Rinaldi
Pension awareness and nation-wide auto-enrolment: the Italian
experience
N° 103/10
Fabio Bagliano
Claudio Morana
The Great Recession: US dynamics and spillovers to the world
economy
N° 102/10
Nuno Cassola
Claudio Morana
The 2007-? financial crisis: a money market perspective
N° 101/10
Tetyana Dubovyk
Macroeconomic Aspects of Italian Pension Reforms of 1990s
N° 100/10
Laura Piatti
Giuseppe Rocco
L’educazione e la comunicazione previdenziale - Il caso italiano
N° 99/10
Fabio Bagliano
Claudio Morana
The effects of US economic and financial crises on euro area
convergence
N° 98/10
Annamaria Lusardi
Daniel Schneider
Peter Tufano
The Economic Crisis and Medical Care Usage
N° 97/10
Carlo Maccheroni
Tiziana Barugola
E se l’aspettativa di vita continuasse la sua crescita? Alcune
ipotesi per le generazioni italiane 1950-2005
N° 96/10
Riccardo Calcagno
Mariacristina Rossi
Portfolio Choice and Precautionary Savings
N° 95/10
Flavia Coda Moscarola
Elsa Fornero
Mariacristina Rossi
Parents/children “deals”: Inter-Vivos Transfers and Living
Proximity
N° 94/10
John A. List
Sally Sadoff
Mathis Wagner
So you want to run an experiment, now what? Some Simple
Rules of Thumb for Optimal Experimental Design
N° 93/10
Mathis Wagner
The Heterogeneous Labor Market Effects of Immigration
N° 92/10
Rob Alessie
Michele Belloni
Retirement choices in Italy: what an option value model tells us
N° 91/09
Annamaria Lusardi
Olivia S. Mitchell
Vilsa Curto
Financial Literacy among the Young:
Evidence and Implications for Consumer Policy
N° 90/09
Annamaria Lusardi
Olivia S. Mitchell
How Ordinary Consumers Make Complex Economic Decisions:
Financial Literacy and Retirement Readiness
N° 89/09
Elena Vigna
Mean-variance inefficiency of CRRA and CARA utility
functions for portfolio selection in defined contribution pension
schemes
N° 88/09
Maela Giofré
Convergence of EMU Equity Portfolios
N° 87/09
Elsa Fornero
Annamaria Lusardi
Chiara Monticone
Adequacy of Saving for Old Age in Europe
N° 86/09
Margherita Borella
Flavia Coda Moscarola
Microsimulation of Pension Reforms: Behavioural versus
Nonbehavioural Approach
N° 85/09
Cathal O’Donoghue
John Lennon
Stephen Hynes
The Life-Cycle Income Analysis Model (LIAM): A Study of a
Flexible Dynamic Microsimulation Modelling Computing
Framework
N° 84/09
Luca Spataro
Il sistema previdenziale italiano dallo shock petrolifero del 1973
al Trattato di Maastricht del 1993
N° 83/09
Annamaria Lusardi
Peter Tufano
Debt Literacy, Financial Experiences, and Overindebtedness
N° 82/09
Carolina Fugazza
Massimo Guidolin
Giovanna Nicodano
Time and Risk Diversification in Real Estate Investments:
Assessing the Ex Post Economic Value
N° 81/09
Fabio Bagliano
Claudio Morana
Permanent and Transitory Dynamics in House Prices and
Consumption: Cross-Country Evidence
N° 80/08
Claudio Campanale
Learning, Ambiguity and Life-Cycle Portfolio Allocation
N° 79/08
Annamaria Lusardi
Increasing the Effectiveness of Financial Education in the
Workplace
N° 78/08
Margherita Borella
Giovanna Segre
Le pensioni dei lavoratori parasubordinati: prospettive dopo un
decennio di gestione separata
N° 77/08
Giovanni Guazzarotti
Pietro Tommasino
The Annuity Market in an Evolving Pension System: Lessons
from Italy
N° 76/08
Riccardo Calcagno
Elsa Fornero
Mariacristina Rossi
The Effect of House Prices on Household Saving: The Case of
Italy
N° 75/08
Harold Alderman
Johannes Hoogeveen
Mariacristina Rossi
Preschool Nutrition and Subsequent Schooling Attainment:
Longitudinal Evidence from Tanzania
N° 74/08
Maela Giofré
Information Asymmetries and Foreign Equity Portfolios:
Households versus Financial Investors
N° 73/08
Michele Belloni
Rob Alessie
The Importance of Financial Incentives on Retirement Choices:
New Evidence for Italy
N° 72/08
Annamaria Lusardi
Olivia Mitchell
Planning and Financial Literacy: How Do Women Fare?
N° 71/07
Flavia Coda Moscarola
Women participation and caring decisions: do different
institutional frameworks matter? A comparison between Italy and
The Netherlands
N° 70/07
Radha Iyengar
Giovanni Mastrobuoni
The Political Economy of the Disability Insurance. Theory and
Evidence of Gubernatorial Learning from Social Security
Administration Monitoring
N° 69/07
Carolina Fugazza
Massimo Guidolin
Giovanna Nicodano
Investing in Mixed Asset Portfolios: the Ex-Post Performance
N° 68/07
Massimo Guidolin
Giovanna Nicodano
Small Caps in International Diversified Portfolios
N° 67/07
Carolina Fugazza
Maela Giofré
Giovanna Nicodano
International Diversification and Labor Income Risk
N° 66/07
Maarten van Rooij
Annamaria Lusardi
Rob Alessie
Financial Literacy and Stock Market Participation
N° 65/07
Annamaria Lusardi
Household Saving Behavior: The Role of Literacy, Information
and Financial Education Programs
(Updated version June 08: “Financial Literacy: An Essential Tool
for Informed Consumer Choice?”)
N° 64/07
Carlo Casarosa
Luca Spataro
Rate of Growth of Population, Saving and Wealth in the Basic
Life-cycle Model when the Household is the Decision Unit
N° 63/07
Claudio Campanale
Life-Cycle Portfolio Choice: The Role of Heterogeneous UnderDiversification
N° 62/07
Margherita Borella
Elsa Fornero
Mariacristina Rossi
Does Consumption Respond to Predicted Increases in Cash-onhand Availability? Evidence from the Italian “Severance Pay”
N° 61/07
Irina Kovrova
Effects of the Introduction of a Funded Pillar on the Russian
Household Savings: Evidence from the 2002 Pension Reform
N° 60/07
Riccardo Cesari
Giuseppe Grande
Fabio Panetta
La Previdenza Complementare in Italia:
Caratteristiche, Sviluppo e Opportunità per i Lavoratori
N° 59/07
Riccardo Calcagno
Roman Kraeussl
Chiara Monticone
An Analysis of the Effects of the Severance Pay Reform on
Credit to Italian SMEs
N° 58/07
Elisa Luciano
Jaap Spreeuw
Elena Vigna
Modelling Stochastic Mortality for Dependent Lives
N° 57/07
Giovanni Mastrobuoni
Matthew Weinberg
Heterogeneity in Intra-Monthly Consumption. Patterns, SelfControl, and Savings at Retirement
N° 56/07
John A. Turner
Satyendra Verma
Why Some Workers Don’t Take 401(k) Plan Offers:
Inertia versus Economics
N° 55/06
Antonio Abatemarco
On the Measurement of Intra-Generational Lifetime
Redistribution in Pension Systems
N° 54/06
Annamaria Lusardi
Olivia S. Mitchell
Baby Boomer Retirement Security: The Roles of Planning,
Financial Literacy, and Housing Wealth
N° 53/06
Giovanni Mastrobuoni
Labor Supply Effects of the Recent Social Security Benefit Cuts:
Empirical Estimates Using Cohort Discontinuities
N° 52/06
Luigi Guiso
Tullio Jappelli
Information Acquisition and Portfolio Performance
N° 51/06
Giovanni Mastrobuoni
The Social Security Earnings Test Removal. Money Saved or
Money Spent by the Trust Fund?
N° 50/06
Andrea Buffa
Chiara Monticone
Do European Pension Reforms Improve the Adequacy of
Saving?
N° 49/06
Mariacristina Rossi
Examining the Interaction between Saving and Contributions to
Personal Pension Plans. Evidence from the BHPS
N° 48/06
Onorato Castellino
Elsa Fornero
Public Policy and the Transition to Private Pension Provision in
the United States and Europe
N° 47/06
Michele Belloni
Carlo Maccheroni
Actuarial Neutrality when Longevity Increases: An Application
to the Italian Pension System
N° 46/05
Annamaria Lusardi
Olivia S. Mitchell
Financial Literacy and Planning: Implications for Retirement
Wellbeing
N° 45/05
Claudio Campanale
Increasing Returns to Savings and Wealth Inequality
N° 44/05
Henrik Cronqvist
Advertising and Portfolio Choice
N° 43/05
John Beshears
James J. Choi
David Laibson
The Importance of Default Options for Retirement Saving
Outcomes: Evidence from the United States
Brigitte C. Madrian
N° 42/05
Margherita Borella
Flavia Coda Moscarola
Distributive Properties of Pensions Systems: a Simulation of the
Italian Transition from Defined Benefit to Defined Contribution
N° 41/05
Massimo Guidolin
Giovanna Nicodano
Small Caps in International Equity Portfolios: The Effects of
Variance Risk.
N° 40/05
Carolina Fugazza
Massimo Guidolin
Giovanna Nicodano
Investing for the Long-Run in European Real Estate. Does
Predictability Matter?
N° 39/05
Anna Rita Bacinello
Modelling the Surrender Conditions in Equity-Linked Life
Insurance
N° 38/05
Carolina Fugazza
Federica Teppa
An Empirical Assessment of the Italian Severance Payment
(TFR)
N° 37/04
Jay Ginn
Actuarial Fairness or Social Justice?
A Gender Perspective on Redistribution in Pension Systems
N° 36/04
Laurence J. Kotlikoff
Pensions Systems and the Intergenerational Distribution of
Resources
N° 35/04
Monika Bütler
Olivia Huguenin
Federica Teppa
What Triggers Early Retirement. Results from Swiss Pension
Funds
N° 34/04
Chourouk Houssi
Le Vieillissement Démographique :
Problématique des Régimes de Pension en Tunisie
N° 33/04
Elsa Fornero
Carolina Fugazza
Giacomo Ponzetto
A Comparative Analysis of the Costs of Italian Individual
Pension Plans
N° 32/04
Angelo Marano
Paolo Sestito
Giacomo Ponzetto
Older Workers and Pensioners: the Challenge of Ageing on the
Italian Public Pension System and Labour Market
Risk Aversion and the Utility of Annuities
N° 30/03
Bas Arts
Elena Vigna
A Switch Criterion for Defined Contribution Pension Schemes
N° 29/02
Marco Taboga
The Realized Equity Premium has been Higher than Expected:
Further Evidence
N° 28/02
Luca Spataro
New Tools in Micromodeling Retirement Decisions: Overview
and Applications to the Italian Case
N° 27/02
Reinhold Schnabel
Annuities in Germany before and after the Pension Reform of
2001
N° 26/02
E. Philip Davis
Issues in the Regulation of Annuities Markets
N° 25/02
Edmund Cannon
Ian Tonks
The Behaviour of UK Annuity Prices from 1972 to the Present
N° 24/02
Laura Ballotta
Steven Haberman
Ermanno Pitacco
Valuation of Guaranteed Annuity Conversion Options
N° 22/02
Chris Soares
Mark Warshawsky
Annuity Risk: Volatility and Inflation Exposure in Payments
from Immediate Life Annuities
N° 21/02
Olivia S. Mitchell
David McCarthy
Annuities for an Ageing World
N° 31/03
N° 23/02
Longevity Risk in Living Benefits
N° 20/02
Mauro Mastrogiacomo
Dual Retirement in Italy and Expectations
N° 19/02
Paolo Battocchio
Francesco Menoncin
Optimal Portfolio Strategies with Stochastic Wage Income and
Inflation: The Case of a Defined Contribution Pension Plan
N° 18/02
Francesco Daveri
Labor Taxes and Unemployment: a Survey of the Aggregate
Evidence
N° 17/02
Richard Disney and
Sarah Smith
The Labour Supply Effect of the Abolition of the Earnings Rule
for Older Workers in the United Kingdom
N° 16/01
Estelle James and
Xue Song
Annuities Markets Around the World: Money’s Worth and Risk
Intermediation
N° 15/01
Estelle James
How Can China Solve ist Old Age Security Problem? The
Interaction Between Pension, SOE and Financial Market Reform
N° 14/01
Thomas H. Noe
Investor Activism and Financial Market Structure
N° 13/01
Michela Scatigna
Institutional Investors, Corporate Governance and Pension Funds
N° 12/01
Roberta Romano
Less is More: Making Shareholder Activism a Valuable
Mechanism of Corporate Governance
N° 11/01
Mara Faccio and Ameziane
Lasfer
Institutional Shareholders and Corporate Governance: The Case
of UK Pension Funds
N° 10/01
Vincenzo Andrietti and Vincent Pension Portability and Labour Mobility in the United States.
Hildebrand
New Evidence from the SIPP Data
N° 9/01
Hans Blommestein
Ageing, Pension Reform, and Financial Market Implications in
the OECD Area
N° 8/01
Margherita Borella
Social Security Systems and the Distribution of Income: an
Application to the Italian Case
N° 7/01
Margherita Borella
The Error Structure of Earnings: an Analysis on Italian
Longitudinal Data
N° 6/01
Flavia Coda Moscarola
The Effects of Immigration Inflows on the Sustainability of the
Italian Welfare State
N° 5/01
Vincenzo Andrietti
Occupational Pensions and Interfirm Job Mobility in the
European Union. Evidence from the ECHP Survey
N° 4/01
Peter Diamond
Towards an Optimal Social Security Design
N° 3/00
Emanuele Baldacci
Luca Inglese
Le caratteristiche socio economiche dei pensionati in Italia.
Analisi della distribuzione dei redditi da pensione (only available
in the Italian version)
N° 2/00
Pier Marco Ferraresi
Elsa Fornero
Social Security Transition in Italy: Costs, Distorsions and (some)
Possible Correction
N° 1/00
Guido Menzio
Opting Out of Social Security over the Life Cycle